You may have not noticed it, but the use of local content
requirements (LCRs) has gone up for years. They
are used by developed as well as developing countries. LCRs aim to promote the
use of local inputs. They also serve the purpose of fostering domestic
industries. BRICS and many other emerging countries are frequent users of LCRs,
together with the US.
However, LCRs can be highly damaging for the economy. While
LCRs might have the perceived benefit of creating industry activity and local
employment, these gains or often generated in the short-term. LCRs are most
likely to have a damaging economic impact that is wider in the long run. This
harmful impact therefore evolves over time, which eventually outweighs any
specific short run gain they can create.
ECIPE’s new
study with undersigned contribution estimates the damaging impacts of
LCRs for BRICS countries. Our team has translated their negative effects into
so-called ad valorem equivalents (AVE). This is a methodological concept that allows one to readily
compare the adverse impact of any non-tariff barrier (NTB) such as an LCR with
a tariff. Our study has taken LCRs in the heavy vehicle sector as a case in
point.
The results are presented in the figure below. They show
that Brazil and Russia apply the most distortive LCRs for heavy vehicles. The
two countries have an estimated increase of their import price of 15.6 and 11.1
percent respectively. China and South Africa both show low AVEs of 4.5 and 3.3
percent respectively. India’s LCRs are least harmful as it shows an AVE estimate
of 2.2 percent.
Source: ECIPE calculations, based on ECIPE LCR BRICS database; WITS/UNCTAD TRAINS
Strikingly, there is more to this story. The figure also
shows the opposing relationship between LCRs and tariffs: apart from Brazil,
countries with low tariffs in the heavy vehicles sector actually have higher levels of
distorting LCRs. Conversely, countries with higher tariffs have lower levels of
distorting LCRs. Brazil is an outlier in these sense that it has both high
tariffs and high levels of distorting LCRs.
When you come to think of it, this may not be a big surprise. Over the
years tariffs have gone down through unilateral, multilateral or bilateral
deals governments have sealed. But this trend has unlikely satisfied everyone
in the economy. One way for government to compensate actors, constituencies or
firms active in import competing industries is by raising murky NTBs, of
which LCRs are one of them.
We furthermore estimate the wider economic impact that LCRs have
inside as well as outside this sub-sector of motor vehicles. The results indeed
show that although LCRs may have a short-term effect of increasing output in
the targeted sector, for the rest of the economy, including consumes, a much
bigger negative effect takes place. This is important to note as everyone else
suffers from LCRs.
For instance, the identified LCRs are estimated to restrict
imports of heavy vehicles by -21% in Brazil and -12% in Russia because of their increased import prices (for the other BRICS countries this varies between -9.3%
and -3.7%). LCRs therefore benefits the domestic heavy vehicle industry in
these countries by shielding inefficient firms in the sector from any external
competition.
However, the consequence is that the LCRs in the BRICS countries will in turn have the pernicious
effect of (a) reducing exports of heavy vehicles themselves;
(b) increasing prices for firms who need heavy vehicles as an intermediate good; and
finally (c) decreasing production of closely related industries using
heavy-vehicles (in part because of higher prices).
In the end, the final user, that is the consumer, is worse off in the BRICS countries
In the end, the final user, that is the consumer, is worse off
No comments:
Post a Comment