A couple of
questions have been posed regarding the graph I developed for Wallonia’s trade share
with Canada. Here are some of my explanations and further thoughts on the issue.
One remark that
was made related to the fact that these figures would be biased because
Flanders has Antwerp. Antwerp, like Rotterdam, are known for what
trade-economists call their “entrepôt”
activities. These two cities import lots of goods because of their ports, store
them, and then re-export them again to other parts of Europe, i.e. the
hinterland, which I indeed allude to in the piece.
This bias is
true, but only to some extent. The NBB source that separates regional trade between
Flanders and Wallonia on the one hand and Canada on the other presents data at
a level where these imports and re-exports of non-residential entities are
excluded, i.e. pure transit trade appears to be out.
Transit
trade of goods that arrive in Flanders’s main port are therefore as it seems left out. The difference is a quarter. Although I doubt all transit
trade is excluded from here, it’s nonetheless hard to imagine that this change
is solely made up by non-residential expats. A big chunk must come from
“Antwerp”.
However, these
clean regional trade numbers do not match with trade figures from Eurostat /
OECD, which is needed to sort out the two Belgian regions’ EU trade share with
Canada. They provide data including these entrepôt activities.
Now, since
Eurostat / OECD figures includes this transit trade one must take a consistent
share of Belgian’s total trade as part of the EU with Canada because other
countries such as the Netherlands also have transit trade. Belgian’s share in total EU-Canada trade is 7.55 percent, which includes both imports and exports.
Going back
to the NBB data, Belgian’s regional division of trade is 1.38 percent imports
and 9.5 percent exports for Wallonia against Flanders. The latter percentage
was also shown in Politico’s bar chart, which actually got me started. I used
similar way of coming to a regional total trade division by summing up imports
and exports, which gives a figure of 4.4 percent, but added Brussels and rounded up to 6 percent.
With these
numbers at hand, one can sort out the rough back-of-the-envelope calculation which I give in the pie chart. Simple rough computations, yet indicative with
the available information at hand. Of course, all this computed with real trade
data from all these sources.
Although
Wallonia’s part could be bigger by being even more generous, I don’t think that
would significantly differ the main pattern. My guess is that Wallonia just
trades much less precisely for reasons that is has not a port, even after correcting for Antwerp’s pure
transit re-exports.
Today’s
trade is intermediate input trade with unfinished goods that cross borders
multiple times around the globe. It is also called global supply or value chain trade. In
total, almost 60 percent of total trade is intermediate. In each stage of the
production line the input is imported and processed by adding value and then re-exported
again to finally arrive at the point of destination.
Flanders
has a port, but also many industries that import intermediate goods, process
them, and quickly export them again. Value is therefore added, which should not
be disregarded. On the contrary, the global value chain literature has made a huge turn-around in trade studies by precisely emphasizing this type of trade, and warns
us not to stay focused on finished goods trade.
Hence, these
questions touch upon a more fundamental issue. Leaving out pure entrepôt
activities is understandable as I have done to the extent possible, but one
should not forget that precisely because Flanders has a port it trades so much
more in other types of goods as well, not only pure transit goods.
On yet
another level these questions also hint to the fact that trade figures are in
“gross” terms, which also plays a role for Wallonia’s dwarfed numbers. Gross
figures count the total value of the good twice: when it comes in, and when it
goes out at greater values.
If
anything, this constitutes the real distortion and the recent value-added approach
that the trade literature has been taking is a good start to correct this
interpretation. Unfortunately, however, developments in this area are still far
away from sorting out regional value-added trade and for most recent years.
Turning to
the figure itself, the purpose of the graph is to negate the fact that the Wallonia
government claims it is a matter of trade, i.e. an economic issue. On the
contrary, it exports 4 times more to Canada than it imports from it.
Moreover, opposition
to trade agreement often revolves around industries that would rather not like
to see greater levels of competing goods coming into their country. However, it’s hard
to think that the 1.38 percent of Wallonia’s import share from Canada within Belgium comes along with that
strong efforts of lobbying.
Therefore,
other reasons must be at play which was also pointed out by Paul de Grauwe. Domestic politics is an obvious
candidate, but I would also add the role of ideas.
An often-heard worry in Wallonia is that with trade agreements in place big multinationals are coming and therefore can form a threat. Even though big foreign companies bring a lot of good to the local economy, these arguments should nonetheless be taken seriously.
An often-heard worry in Wallonia is that with trade agreements in place big multinationals are coming and therefore can form a threat. Even though big foreign companies bring a lot of good to the local economy, these arguments should nonetheless be taken seriously.
Yet my last
check was that the Commission did take these concerns into account,
particularly regarding the ISDS. So again, my guess is that it all comes down to domestic politics.
No comments:
Post a Comment